Farm Size and Productivity Nexus Farmers’ Welfare in Burundi
Sanctus
Niragira1*, Jan Brusselaers1, Jeroen Buysse2,
Jos Van Orshoven3, Jean Ndimubandi1, Marijke D'Haese2
1Department
of Rural Development, University of Burundi, Burundi
2Department
of Agricultural Economics, Ghent University, Belgium
3Department
of Earth &
Environmental Science, University of Leuven, Belgium
*Corresponding author: Sanctus Niragira, Department
of Rural Development, University of Burundi, Burundi. Tel: +25771509242;
Email: Niragsnctus@gmail.com
Received Date: 16 April, 2018; Accepted Date: 04 May, 2018; Published Date: 14 May, 2018
Citation:
This paper presents an
economic analysis of small-scale agricultural production efficiency and
household welfare in Burundi. We used recent advances in data envelopment
analysis (robust DEA) to generate standard and bootstrap-bias-corrected
technical efficiency scores for a nationwide sample of farms in the country.
Next the correlation between these farm efficiency scores and household poverty
levels was checked. Finally, an instrumental variable approach was used to
assess the link between household welfare and farm productivity. Findings
highlight that smaller farms are more efficient than the larger farms. Yet,
given their small size, this efficiency level is not sufficient to raise the
farm income above the poverty line which raises concerns about small farms’
viability. Most of them are too small and agriculture can no longer provide a
realistic livelihood for the household to earn a living. As a consequence, most
of the land-constrained household are poor and food insecure despite their
higher productivity. Both consumption and income appear as increasing functions
of the farm size. As such, it is hard to appreciate how the inverse
relationship between farm size and land productivity can strengthen nearly
landless households or how livelihoods can be sustained in small scale farms of
Burundi. Fundamental changes in the farming systems and agricultural policy are
necessary to increase the scope for sustainable smallholder-led agriculture and
its spill-over effects on the country’s economy.
Keywords: Burundi;
Efficiency; Food Security; Landholdings; Small Scale; Welfare
Introduction
The potential of
smallholder agriculture to create employment in rural areas, to generate
income, and to contribute to household food security has been well documented
in many developing countries [1,2]. Since 1964, when Schultz formulated the “poor-but-efficient”
hypothesis, smallholder farmers attracted the attention of researchers, donors
and decision makers alike. By agreeing that small-scale farmers are more
rational, compared to the large landowners in allocating their scarce
resources, improving the livelihoods of these households becomes a central aim
of agriculture-led development. An impressive body of literature confirms that
small-scale farms are efficient by showing an inverse relationship between farm
size and yield [3,4]. Better efficiency on small-scale farms is partly attributed to
the abundant family labour per unit of land. Family workers are typically more
motivated than hired workers and provide self-supervised high quality labour [5]. In addition, small
farms achieve higher productivity with lower capital input compared to large
farms, which is very important in countries where land and capital are scarce
relatively to labour [6]
and markets for credit and inputs are imperfect.
Empirical evidence suggests that support to small farms should not
only be motivated by efficiency reasons but also because family farms are
needed to maintain stability in the community, to secure sustainability of
agricultural production and to stimulate local rural economic growth.
Productive activities on small-scale farms as well as their labour
mobilization, consumption patterns, ecological knowledge and common interests
in long-term maintenance of the farm as a resource, contribute significantly to
a stable and lasting local economy [7].
Smallholder farms contribute to reducing unemployment, provide a more equitable
distribution of income and generate an effective demand for products and
services from other sectors of the economy [8].
By spending substantial shares of the extra income on locally produced
non-agricultural goods and services, they contribute to markets and production
of often labour-intensive goods [2,9,10].
In turn, these demand-driven growth linkages provide better
income-earning opportunities for the most vulnerable groups including nearly
landless farmers and workers. Hence, both direct and indirect effects arising
from supporting small farms contribute to the overall reduction in rural
poverty and food insecurity [1,6] as these households account for large shares of the rural poor [11]. Moreover, growth in
the smallholder farm sector adds to a more vibrant rural non-farm economy which
in turn could constrain the rural-urban migration [6]. However, the viability
of smallholder farms today is greatly challenged. They are confronted with
trade-distorting agricultural policies and the shift toward increasingly
integrated and consumer driven markets as part of market liberalization and
globalization [6,12,13]. Also access to
sufficient land is a great concern [14].
In many poorer countries, the continuous spatial subdivision of
landholdings has reached levels where a growing number of subsistence farms are
unable to achieve their primary goal to secure the families’ food and income [15]. Hence, a pertinent
question is if and how farm size affects the ability of the farmers to provide
a decent living to the household and further ensure communities’ long-term
economic sustainability? According to Hazell, the minimum acceptable size of a
farm depends on the possibility in complementing income from farm activities
with non-farm income [6].
At a certain level of farm size division, farms could get so small that
production becomes too low to warrant their farming activity. Non-farm income
is then needed to survive, but non-farm income earning opportunities may be
very scarce especially in the rural areas of least developed countries. Jayne
et al. (2003) [14] emphasised the growing
number of landless and nearly landless farms leading ultimately to a rapid exodus
from the countryside despite the low accommodation capacity and high rates of
unemployment in African cities.
Against this background,
this study assesses the link between farm size, productivity and household
welfare in the context of highly fragmented landholdings of Burundi.
Demographic pressure has caused shortages of agricultural lands. In addition,
the intensive cultivation led to serious soil erosion and fertility problems [16], and therefore put
limits on the scope of sustainable intensification. Yet, the agricultural
sector is considered to be the backbone of the country’s economy and its
problems hence call for comprehensive public interventions [17].
A study by Verschelde (2013) [18] in two Northern provinces of Burundi found an inverse relationship
between farm size and land productivity while showing a strong correlation
between farm size and household food security [18]. This inverse relationship has been confirmed for other
smallholder farming systems too. The findings may not come as surprise if one
assumes the limits of scale economies due to limited mechanisation, input use
and market. Yet, how small, a small farm is allowed to be as to secure
household survival? For numerous households, farm income is not sufficient to
properly remunerate the farmer’s work nor to support household food and
non-food needs [17]. Therefore, even though smaller farms are considered more
productive, the key question for the farm family is in the end whether the
total income generated and food produced allows them to feed their families and
to cross the poverty line.
Higher farm productivity may allow an exit from poverty, if the
size of production and the income generated is sufficiently large; or in other
words if the farms are of a minimal size [19]. Access to land is generally regarded as a key issue for
sustainable livelihoods in Burundi [20]. Scholars view access to land as a significant determinant of
food security, vulnerability to risks and shocks, and income potential [21]. A particular question
is also how efficiency levels influence welfare given a certain farming system
and land area. This relationship may differ from the one between land area and
efficiency. This basically answers the question whether it is possible for a
household to gain welfare through improving the farming system’s efficiency
given the land it has available.
The link between the inverse relationship of farm size and
efficiency, and a discussion on minimum scale to secure sufficient quantities
of food for the family, is not often made. We want to close this gap in
literature. This study makes at least two contributions to literature. First it
analyses the production levels and efficiency of production in terms of energy
and macronutrient levels. The production and income recalculated in food
availability and accessibility allow investigating farm production from a
nutrition-sensitive agriculture perspective. We calculate the relationship
between farm size, efficiency levels, production size, income and food
security. Second, we add a question of minimum scale to the inverse
relationship literature. As far as we know this has been overlooked in
literature so far. We use a dataset of information collected by the Ministry of
Agriculture from farms across Burundi. We apply a Data Envelopment Analyses
(bootstrapped to increase robustness of the results) to calculate efficiencies
which are then compared to absolute levels of production and income. We
estimate how increase in efficiency, given the land area, can influence farm
household’s welfare levels. The key welfare variable for this study is farm
income per adult equivalent. Despite that income is considered less desirable
in measuring consumption-based welfare, it is generally accepted as a key
indicator of household economic activity and welfare [14].
Study Methodology
Data
This study uses data from a recent agricultural survey available
from the National Statistical Bureau of Burundi (ISTEEBU). The nationally
representative survey was conducted in the 16 provinces of the country on a
sample of 2560 farm households during the cropping year 2011-2012. In each of
the 16 provinces, 20 collines (administrative demarcation) were randomly
selected and in each colline, 8 farm households were randomly chosen to
participate in the survey. The main purpose of the survey was to update agricultural
statistics in the country. The survey included 14 sections with questions
related to farm production, household characteristics, income generating
activities and livestock keeping. Households were visited several times during
all three agricultural seasons. The data on agriculture was complemented by
data on living-conditions collected by the World Bank on the same farm
household sample. For some variables, we noticed measurement and encoding
errors which prevented identification and therefore merging of the datasets1. Farm households which
could not be matched were removed from the dataset, resulting in a sample of
2130 farm households. Note that the province of Bujumbura mairie (which
is the most important urban area in the country) was not considered in the
survey due to the relatively minor role it plays in agricultural production of
the country.
Variables Included in the Study
Not all available data were used in this study. Only variables
related to household size and composition, agricultural investments and annual
production were considered. Household composition is given in number of adult
equivalents taking into account the household structure. The Adult Equivalents
are created to normalize the nutritional needs of different family members in a
household based on age and gender [22,23]. Pregnancy and breastfeeding were not included in the study due
to lack of related information in the dataset. With regard to farm production,
we valued food crops production at their market prices, irrespective of whether
crops were sold, consumed by the household or exchanged through social networks2. The quantity of each
crop was multiplied by an average market price3 of the respective crop
because individual farm-gate prices were missing. They are highly volatile
while only very limited amounts of produce are sold in most farm households. We
consider that this price represents the real amount of money that farmers would
have to pay to acquire the products on the market. Annual production was also
valued in terms of calorie and food macronutrients (proteins and fat contents)
in order to aggregate the production in a single unit that can be compared with
the household food needs. Production quantity of each crop was multiplied by
respective approximate content in calories, proteins and fat issued by FAO4.The production of
banana was taken separately because banana can be considered a semi-cash crop
as it is mostly used to produce the locally well-known and highly marketed
banana wine/beer [24]. Cash crops are coffee, tea and cotton, and related income and
non-farm income were reported by farmers during the interviews.
Land size, labour and cost of purchased inputs (agricultural
expenditures) were included as production factors. For land, the total farm
area that was used for growing crops in the three cropping seasons of the
2011-2012 agricultural year was calculated. The impact of land fragmentation
was assessed because a single farm in Burundi consists of numerous spatially
separated parcels. Whereas some authors consider land fragmentation as an
obstacle that causes inefficiencies in production and hence reduces income of
farmers, others view it as an advantage for farmers to mitigate risk and
optimise the cropping activities calendar [25]. Land fragmentation was captured by Simmons index which is the
sum of different plot areas squared divided by the square of total cropping
area Si2/(Si)2; with Si: area of plot i). This index varies between zero and
one, with the higher values indicating lower fragmentation [25].
Two different sources of labour were considered, namely family
labour measured as the number of adult family workers, and hired labour
expressed in labour expenditure. Although the former is an imperfect proxy of
the effective time spent by family workers on the farm household, it was used
as we lacked more detailed data. Most of farm work is done by family members.
Due to the absence of an alternative labour market to agriculture,
over-employment on own farms is very common. One may assume that the marginal
productivity is almost zero in such case which makes it difficult to calculate
the opportunity cost for labour. The extra labour is sometimes hired, but paid
very low wages. Hence, the true value of the labour is very difficult to
quantify and the wage levels are used as proxies.
Purchased inputs concerned expenditures for seeds and chemicals.
Generally, seeds and seedlings used in agricultural production in Burundi are
mostly local varieties taken from previous harvests. Yet, farmers often
complement the seed stock with purchases or simply buy all the seeds if the
quantity (previously) harvested was not sufficiently enough to deduct the
seeds. Farmers may also choose to buy improved seeds to enhance productivity.
Farmers buy fertilizers and pesticides even though at less extent.
Analytical Framework
The model presented in this paper is based on a Data Envelopment
Analysis that generates efficiency scores for each farm in the sample related
to the best performing peer farm. These efficiency scores are then compared to
the poverty levels by farm size. We improve the traditional DEA and poverty
measures in three ways: first, we used robust DEA model to generate standard
and bootstrap-bias-corrected technical efficiency scores among farms. We used
an approach for bootstrapping proposed by Simar and Wilson (2000) [26] which simulates the
effect of noise in the data on efficiency evaluation. Given the stochastic
nature of the agricultural production and the possible occurrence of outliers,
this more robust modelling approach significantly improves the estimation of
predicted behaviour of scarce resource use in different policy contexts or in
different production activities.
Second, the P-alpha measure of poverty, developed in 1984 by
Foster, Greer and Thorbecke, was used to define the poverty levels (poverty
incidence, gaps and severity) among farm households. We used a poverty
threshold estimated for Burundi by Bundervoet (2006) [27] as the poverty line.
Based on a consumption bundle deemed adequate to satisfy basic needs, the food
poverty line was estimated at 14.95 USD5 per adult equivalent per month to which a minimum amount of 3.3
USD per month for non-farm needs was added. This sums up to 18.25 USD per adult
equivalent [27]. With an exchange rate
of 1238 BIF6 to the USD, the overall poverty line was defined at 22 593.5 BIF
per adult equivalent per month or 271 122 BIF (219USD) per adult equivalent per
year.
Third, a regression analysis was implemented to assess the driving
factors of household welfare measured as household income per adult equivalent.
An Instrumental Variable (IV)
regression approach was used to deal with reversed causality between farm
efficiency and household welfare causing problems of endogeneity. This IV
approach is used for confounding control [28]. The principle is that variables correlated with some outcomes
through their effect on other variables, are explicitly excluded from some
equations and included in others [29] in a system of equation known as structural equations models.
Efficiency analysis
We used a non-parametric procedure to estimate the farms’
production frontier. Non-parametric approaches are sometimes preferred over
parametric methods because the latter requires assumptions such on the
mathematical specification of the functional form of the production [30]. DEA methods have
gained greater momentum after the pioneering work by Charnes et al. (1978) [31] for a Constant Return
to Scale (CRS) version of DEA, which was later extended by Banker et al. (1984)
[32] to a Variable Return to
Scale (VRS) DEA framework. The individual technical efficiency scores are
calculated using mathematical programming techniques where the solutions
satisfy inequality constraints of all decision making units involved.
The CRS restriction assumes that all farms in the analysis are
performing at an optimal scale. However, technical efficiency scores reported
under CRS are biased by scale efficiencies. The Variable Return to Scale (VRS)
implies that each unit is compared to a ‘peer group’ consisting of a linear
combination of efficient production units with similar size [33]. This study uses a VRS
specification.
Mathematically, the model is represented as follows [34], given column vectors
of p inputs (denoted by x∈R+p) and of q outputs (denoted
by y∈R+q)
, the production set of physically attainable points (x,y) is given by:
Ψ=[(x,y)∈R+p+q|x can produce y)] (1)
This can be described as
either an input-oriented set (minimizing the proportional input variables while
remaining within the envelopment space) defined as ∀ y∈Ψ,
X(y)=[(x∈R+p|(x,y)∈Ψ]
(2)
Or an output oriented
set (maximizing the proportional increase in the output vector) defined as ∀ y∈Ψ,
Y(x)=[(y∈R+q|(x,y)∈Ψ]
(3)
The choice of any
particular orientation only has a minor influence upon the reported efficiency
scores [35]. The radial
(input-oriented) efficiency boundary (efficient frontier) is then defined by:
∂X(y)=[x|x∈X(y),θx∉X(y)
∀
0<θ<1] (4)
The Farell input measure
of efficiency for a production unit working at level (x0,y0) is defined as:
θ(x0,y0)=inf [x0∈X(y0)] (5)
=inf[(θx0,y0)∈Ψ]
And given an output
level y, and an input mix (a direction) expressed by the vector x, the
efficiency level of inputs is determined by: x∂(y)=θ(x,y)x, which is the
projection of (x,y) on the efficient boundary ∂Ψ, along the ray x and
orthogonal to the vector y.
The same algorithm can be applied to the output space where the
output boundary ∂Y(x) is defined for all x∈Ψ; as:
∂Y(x)=[y|y∈Y(x),⋌y∉Y(x)
∀⋌>1] (6)
Then the Farell output
measure of efficiency for a production unit working at level (x0,y0) is defined
as:
⋌(x0,y0)=sup[(x0,⋌y0)∈Ψ] (7)
The efficient level of
output, for the input level x and for the direction of the output vector
determined by y is given by y∂(x)=⋌(x,y)y .
Note that the frontier Ψ
is unique; ∂X(x) and ∂Y(y) are two different ways of describing it [34,36].
Robust optimization
All deviations from the frontier are considered as inefficiencies
in the standard DEA which makes the approach unable to accommodate measurement
errors and it is extremely sensitive to outliers [36,37]. To overcome those problems, researchers started to incorporate
stochastic considerations into DEA models [26,34,38-41]. The bootstrapping approach was first introduced to the standard
DEA model by Simar (1992). Henceforth, the stochastic programming based on
robust optimization became a common approach to handle uncertainty and is
preferred due to its applicability [42]. Based on statistically well-defined models, the method allows
for robust estimation of the production frontier as well as of the
corresponding efficiency scores [33,43]. Bootstrapping investigates the reliability of the data by
creating a pseudo-replicate data set using Monte Carlo approximation, which
provides a better estimation of parameters of the interest. The bootstrap
distribution will mimic the standard unknown sampling distribution of the
estimators of interest resulting in changes in the ranking of bias-corrected
efficiency scores from the standard efficiency scores. The DEA bootstrapping
process is well documented in [26,34].
The robust DEA model was used to estimate input-oriented measures
of technical efficiency with variable return to scale. The production
activities are disaggregated into following inputs: area cropped, agriculture
investment (expenditure on seeds, labour, fertilizers and pesticides), and
labour expressed in number of adult persons (active) in the household; and
three outputs: food production (calories), total banana production (kg) and
cash crop incomes (section 3.2.2provides more details on the inputs and
outputs).
Household poverty assessments
To evaluate poverty levels among farm households, we used the
P-alpha measure of poverty or the poverty gap index first developed by [44]. The index is based on
the normalised income gap and a predetermined poverty line. With y = (y1, y2,…,
yn) a vector of household (individual) incomes and z > 0 the poverty line,
the expression gi, = z - yiindicates the income shortfall of the ith household. The number
of poor households (income < z) is q = q(y, z) while n = n(y) is the total
number of households. The poverty measure P is given by the following
expression [44]:
P(y,z)=1nz2i=1qgi2
(9)
With H=qn the headcount
ratio, I=i=1qgi2/(qz) the income-gap ratio, the squared coefficient of
variation Cp2 measures inequality and is defined as:
Cp2=iq(y-yi)2/qyp2, where yp=iqyiq , then P(y;z)=H[I2+(1-I)2Cp2] (10)
Cp2is obtained when n
and y are substituted for q and z in the definition of P.
For households whose income is below the poverty line, poverty
measures can be calculated from the following general equation [44]:
Pα=1ni=1q(z-yiz)α (11)
The quantity in
parentheses is the proportional shortfall of expenditure or income to the
poverty line for households living below that line. The parameter α can be
viewed as a measure of poverty aversion: a larger α gives greater emphasis to
the poorest households in the community. For α=0, the measure P0 is simply the
headcount ratio H, where there is no aversion to poverty. When α=1, P1 gives
the depth of poverty or poverty gap (H.I). By setting α=2 , the measure of P is
obtained, which is commonly known as the poverty severity [44-46].
Results and Discussion
Descriptive Statistics on Farm Household
The sample of 2130 farm households retained for the study was
divided into four land quartiles in order to illustrate the possible
relationship between landholding on the one hand and household characteristics,
farm stewardship and productivity, and households’ living conditions on the
other hand. We first give an overview of the basic characteristics captured by
the data (Table
1). The standard
deviations are given in parentheses and significant results from comparisons
are indicated by letters abcd (superscripts) to highlight quartile of farms
which differs from the selected one (a, b, c and d stand for Quartile I, Quartile II, Quartile III and Quartile IV respectively).
The average age of the household head was 42 years with minor
variations over the quartiles. Households were mainly headed by men and the
average household size was 5 people per household. Two to three members worked
on the farm. The number of active persons provides a good indication of the
labour availability in the farms since the family labour is likely to be the
largest labour source for many rural households. To assess the household needs,
the household size was converted into adult equivalent units based on the
number of persons, their age and gender. On average households counted 4.21
adult equivalents, with the largest households found amongst the largest
landowners (Table
2). The table introduces
basic statistics on the farming practices by land quartile. We consider area
used for crop production which is the total amount of land that a household
cultivated during rainy and dry seasons in the corresponding year. Fallow land
and marginal land used for grazing animals or reforestation were excluded from
the analysis. Results reveal that households depend on less than one hectare of
land (0.71 ha on average) for agricultural production.
Clearly, Burundian farmers are poor, they use very little inputs
for a subsistence production on a highly fragmented (average number of plots is
6, range from 1 to26) landholding. The basic input for agricultural production
is land of which the size is limited due to an ever-increasing population. The
distribution of land over the sample is rather unequal which results in a high
number of very small-scale farms. An estimated 47% of the households in the sample
had access to less than 0.5 hectare of agricultural land. Investments in
agricultural production (agricultural expenditures) seem to be closely
correlated with farm size with larger farms allocating more resources and
spending more on inputs, but the overall levels of agricultural expenditure
remain very low. The average yearly expenditure on seeds, labour and chemicals
which included both fertilizers and pesticides amounted to 23.39, 26.23 and
10.57 USD respectively.
Smallholder farmers also lack access to extension and research
services, as well as access to credit. Only 5% of the sample reported to have
received credit during the cropping year of the survey. Despite the fact that
farmers consistently reported a need for credit, microcredit rarely reached
them. Commercial banks are reluctant to lend to farmers due to a lack of
collateral. Agricultural cooperative, which could improve the access to credit [11] are not well developed
neither. Only a small number of farmers interviewed were member of cooperative.
In addition, despite the new institutional engagement of the government to
expand the extension service, few farmers were aware of it. Since 2005, 2803
extension agents received training and were sent to every colline which brings
them in walking distances of most farmers. Yet, only 10% of the farmers’
population interviewed indicated to have received agricultural training during
the cropping year 2011-2012 while almost one third had applied erosion control
on their fields. Technology transfer and adoption are still problematic in the
country due to weak linkages between research services and extension. In
addition, the extension agents are often poorly trained and less motivated [47]. This is confirmed for
other African countries where it was shown that the traditional communication
approach following research had low impact on technology adoption of the users [48].
Household Income and Food Production
The agro-ecological diversity of the country allows for a great
variety of crops to be grown and farms mix several crops on their plots. Of the
fifty-three crops reported in the survey, the shares in overall production (per
land quartile) often most important crops are reported here (Figure 1). Crops like wheat,
banana, beans, potatoes and peanut were mainly produced on larger farms while
small landowners had larger shares in rice production, peas and cassava.
However, these results need to be interpreted carefully because some crops such
as rice are mainly grown in the agro-ecological zones with high population
density and hence small landholdings. Likewise, wheat is grown in the highland
regions where population density is still low.
Globally, the farms in the two quartiles with the smallest
landholdings produced together less (34%) than the farms in the fourth quartile
(39%). The contribution to the overall production of the third land quartile is
low compared to the fourth quartile but significantly higher than the
contribution of the second quartile (20%). The first quartile contributes very
little to the total food production (14%). The annual household income (Table 3), measured as a sum of
the market value of food crops, the cash crop revenue and the non-farm income,
is very low. On average household income is estimated at 650.63 USD per year.
This should cover both food and non-food needs of the family (5 to 6 persons on
average). The value of net crop and farm income (gross income minus
expenditures on input) per hectare, a measure of partial land productivity,
decreases with increasing land size. Whereas land productivity is higher for
smallholders, the labour productivity (farm income per unit of labour) is
higher for larger landholdings. These findings might be influenced by the cost
of hired labour which is more temporary and hard to capture in terms of farm
labourers.
Some studies link low income levels to a vicious circle of
over-exploitation of land leading to continuous nutrient mining and loss of
soil organic matter, and further reductions in the returns to fertilizer use [49]. Burundi is one of
countries with the lowest levels of fertilizer use in Africa as on average only
7.4 kg of fertiliser are applied per hectare of arable land (Worldbank, 2013)7. This is confirmed by
the results in table 2 that on average, only 10.57 USD are spent on fertilizers and
pesticides. With this amount of money, a farmer can afford to buy only 8.1 kg
of fertilizers (if the price of 1.3 USD/kg is assumed, subsidies not included)8. Farmers survive mainly
on their agricultural produce but also on work for wage and self-employment
activities throughout the year. The market value of production (food crops and
cash crops) increases with farm size whereas non-farm/off farm income is
important for household with small farms. Large numbers of small farms seem to
be too small to provide a subsistence living. Roughly 36% of the surveyed
households had one or more members engaged in non-farm employment. An average
household gets 30% of its income from non-farm earnings. This ranges from 19%
in large farms (fourth quartile) to 44% in nearly landless farms (first
quartile). They try to diversify the household’s livelihoods in order to
increase income security, food security and risk coping ability. Yet, non-farm
income and employment opportunities seemed insufficient to adequately
compensate for the low farm income. Local labour markets are not well
developed, and only occasional ill-paid off- and non-farm employment is not
able to improve the food security situation of the households.
Household Food Security
This section presents the food security of the farm households.
While food production was captured by household surveys, only food expenditures
were reported during the interview9. Therefore, food accessibility indicator is used in order to
consider both food production and purchases. We estimated the quantity of food
that households could buy (calories and macronutrients) if they would have to
spend all the income to food. Income is considered as the sum of market value
of the farm production (food and cash crops) and off-farm income.
Bundervoet (2006) [27] used the local and actually observed rural household behaviour to
determine a consumption bundle deemed adequate to satisfy basic consumption
needs. The reference food basket was expressed in terms of calories and
ultimately assigned a monetary value. The food poverty line was calculated at
14.95USD/month (0.498 USD/day) to cover 2500 kcal per adult equivalent (daily),
which enabled us to calculate the calories that each farm household in the
sample could buy with its total income. Table 4 presents figures on percentage of households who meet the minimum
requirements as prescribed by WHO. Only 32% of the sample households had enough
income to cover the caloric needs of the household.
Efficiency and Poverty in Smallholder Farms
Efficiency levels
This section presents the results of the farm efficiency analysis.
The mean efficiency score was 0.53 for the standard DEA and 0.49 for
bias-corrected-scores. A t-test was used to compare the standard and bias-corrected
scores. A significant difference between them at 95% confidence interval
(8.417***) was found, which indicates that the sample distribution was slightly
influenced by stochastic effects. The distribution over the sample of farms
organised by land deciles showed similar trends for both standard and
bias-corrected efficiency scores.
The rest of this paper uses the bias-corrected-efficiency scores.
The results corroborate the low productivity findings which were also addressed
in a recent report of the International Monetary Fund’s [49]. The study highlighted
an important need to improve the farming systems of Burundi. Profit
maximisation models would yield higher efficiency scores [43]. The following graphs
illustrate the distribution of the efficiency scores by the factors affecting
productivity at farm level. The efficiency scores are largely influenced by the
number of adult people working on the farm (Figure 2).
The highest efficiency levels were found among households with
fewer adults and active people in the household. Labour productivity was low
when the number of workers was high while the land to be cultivated was
relatively small. This reflects the high level of underemployment in the study
area reported in previous studies [35,50,51]. Likewise, the distributionof efficiency scores shows a
decreasing trend as the farm size increases. Figure 3 shows how efficiency levels of small farms result in different
frontiers due to the variable return to scale assumptionimplying that each unit
is compared to a ‘peer group’. The general trend is that the level of
efficiency is higher for farms with small landholdings (Figure 3).
These results suggest an Inverse Relationship between farm size
and productivity often highlighted in literature [3,5,18]. IR has been explained by imperfect factor markets leading to
suboptimal resource allocation at the farm level. Labour market imperfection is
often cited as a cause of low productivity on large farms due to supervision
cost of hired labour. Also methodological issues are raised [18]. Another reason often
put forward in literature is that IR emerges from other variables often omitted
from the analysis [52]. In the case of Burundi, land fragmentation is high with an
average Simmons index of 0.21. Farmers own many parcels (6 plots on average)
spatially dispersed all over village areas, in neighbouring villages and in
distant villages. Due to the distance from the farmstead to the plot, parcels
at greater distance are cultivated less intensively. Poor infrastructure, potential
theft and the cost linked to the implementation of soil conservation work
result into farmer’s low motivation to invest in distant plots [25]. This entails
differences in land quality and therefore differences in soil productivity
which clearly could affect the farm’s output levels [53]. Numerous empirical
studies also confirmed that soil quality affects the IR between farm size and
productivity [52,54,55]. Including these
variables in the efficiency analysis did not cancel the IR in an earlier study
on Burundi [18].
Distribution of efficiency score by landholding
This section shows the comparison of efficiency score over the
categories of farms grouped in land deciles. The use of land deciles intended
to give a more detailed view on the distribution of efficiency scores across
sizes of landholdings. They range from 0.41 in the largest decile and 0.63 in
the lowest decile showing that small landholdings are farmed more efficiently.
A one-way ANOVA yielded an F-statistic equals to 20.776***, indicating that
there are statistically significant differences between the land deciles in the
mean efficiency scores. Yet these results cannot show which of the specific
groups differ significantly. The results of a Tukey post-hoc test in SPSS is
shown in table
5. The post-hoc test
identified six groups of farm deciles with significant differences in
efficiency at 95% confidence interval. The four highest deciles (7 264 -
20 902 m² of land) had little
differences in mean efficiency scores. Also the two lowest deciles (1171-2191 m²) seem not to differ
much in terms of efficiency scores. Yet, deciles of smaller farms had a higher
mean efficiency score than the mean of the deciles of the larger farms.
Household poverty levels
The poverty head count index in the sample is 0.75. This result is
in line with the International Monetary Funds’ estimates that 80% of the
farming population lives below the poverty line [49]. This suggests that only 25% of the farming population had income
levels that succeeded to meet household food and non-food needs. The poverty
gap and severity were on average estimated at 0.40 and 0.26 respectively, but,
vary from 0.57 to 0.20 for the poverty gap and 0.42 to 0.10 for the poverty
severity from the lowest to highest land decile (Table 6). The group of farms with the smallest size were worse off in
terms of income.
This section compares
the farm productivity and household welfare indicators. Table 3 suggest that land
ownership had a positive impact on household welfare while affecting the
efficiency negatively. Off-farm income was important for the smallest farms and
its importance decreased as landholding size increased. This is confirmed for
other low income African countries [14]. The land-constrained households have little choice but to
practice unsustainable farming methods, and this is undermining current and
future land productivity. They are more likely to engage in off-farm work but
their labour productivity is typically lower than that of large farms. While
non-farm employment is believed to be a potential avenue to overcome land
constraints among households, the underemployed workforce is typically engaged
in the country’s large informal sector where the level of payment is very low.
Hence, the majority of the more diversified households are poor with the
highest rate of household under the poverty line. It is hard then to appreciate
how the inverse relationship between farm size and land productivity can
strengthen nearly landless households under these conditions or how livelihoods
can be sustained and allow them to cross the poverty line.
Factors Influencing the Household Welfare
The results presented in table 7 give an indication that landholding has a positive impact on
household welfare while being negatively correlated with the farm efficiency.
Yet, what happens if efficiency increases for a given land area? Will it
increase welfare? An econometric model including other household and farm
characteristics as explanatory variables is necessary to gauge the causality
between farm efficiency and household’s welfare. The variables included are:
efficiency, age and gender of the household head, education, active people in
the household, participation in producer cooperatives, access to credit, farm
size and land fragmentation indicator (Simmons index), and agricultural
expenditures. Variables like age and gender of the household head, education,
participation in producer cooperatives, and access to credit did not yield a
significant effect on the household welfare and were not included in the final
model.
The variable efficiency could potentially be considered as
endogenous because the dependent variable income is indirectly used to
calculate the efficiency levels. Hence three instrumental variables are
selected for a 2-stage least squares approach. The variables land, agricultural
expenditures and active people can serve as instruments for the efficiency.
Both agricultural investments and land can be considered as perfectly suitable
instrumental variables but enter also in the main equation of the linear
regression model. This is not the case for the number of active people because
we assume that the redundant availability of labour does have a direct link
with income or welfare.
Table 7 presents the outcomes of the explanatory variables for a farmer’s
welfare, taking into account the endogeneity for variable efficiency and using
number of active people as an instrument. The dependent variable is income per
adult equivalent (BIF/adult equivalent) as an indicator of the household
welfare. These results demonstrate how efficiency positively impacts farmers'
welfare. Hence, keeping all other variables (including for example land)
constant, a farmer can increase household welfare by improving productivity.
Investment and landownership positively impact a farmer’s welfare. Land
concentration seems to negatively impact welfare. This can be due to the fact
that wealthy farmers buy more land which increases their number of plots. Note
however that also for these variables some endogeneity or simultaneity problems
might arise.
Table 7 gives also the Variable Inflation Factor (VIF) which is used to
test for potential multicollinearity. The VIF provides an indication of how
much the variance of the estimated coefficients is inflated when
multicollinearity exists. Values exceeding 4 warrant further investigation,
while values above 10 indicate serious multicollinearity requiring correction10. In our model all VIFs
calculated fall below the cut-off values.
Conclusions and Policy Implications
This study analysed the efficiency and poverty levels of
small-scale farms of Burundi. Despite the significant efficiency in smallholder
agriculture, findings raise concerns about the viability of these very
small-scale farms in the densely populated areas of the country. Given the
rapid population growth, shrinking farm sizes, and declining soil fertility, it
has become very difficult to ensure household food security. Most households
have such small landholdings that agriculture may not be a realistic
possibility for earning a living even if efficiency is high.
This situation is expected to worsen with the continuing land
subdivision due to the inheritance system. As a consequence, poorest household
mainly depend on casual labour income in order to survive. Both consumption and
income appear as increasing functions of landholdings. Yet the scope for
expanding agricultural land is very limited in Burundi, putting limits on the
ability to generate sufficient economic livelihood among households.
Under the current farm practices, smaller farms are more efficient
but given their small size, this efficiency level is insufficient to raise them
above the poverty line. Without fundamental changes in agricultural policies
and farming systems, Burundi has little scope for sustainable smallholder-led
agricultural intensification. In the absence of non-farm income, the source of
rising local incomes would come from supporting agricultural growth among the
small but sustainable farmers (especially farms able to invest in soil
fertility restoration) and thereby catalysing a more successful economic
transformation. This highlights a great need for policies that stimulate
agricultural investment such as credit access, improved markets for
agricultural products and more effective extension services. Moreover, land
markets could allow households to buy and sell land. This would facilitate to
free lands for other farmers.
Sustainable rural employment is critical to encourage the nearly
landless farmers leave farming activities (or to free labour from the farms)
which may benefit those who might remain on farm operations as well. The
transfer of the workforce to other sectors would make agriculture more viable
for at least three reasons: first, it would free up agricultural land. Second,
it would allow more investment in agriculture via transfer of investment or
remittances. Finally, it would improve the market for those farmers who stay in
agriculture. This could boost the potential for agriculture to play its role.
It would create possibilities to generate scale economies and have positive
spill-over effects on the growth of other sectors. This paper does not suggest
abandoning policies directed to very small farms in agriculture, but cautions
that policy in the field of rural development should be rethought for designing
successful poverty reduction strategies.
Notes:
1A partial checking of
the database was done. As result one part of the data was removed as we could
not manage to correct all the errors.
2Previous studies highlighted that 72% of food production were
consumed by the household while 28% were either sold to the market or exchanged
through social network.
3Information on average price is found at the national statistics
Bureau (Annuairestatistique 2013).
4Proximate composition of foods http://www.fao.org/docrep/W0078E/w0078e11.htm#P9840_707166 (last accessed on 20
May 2016)
5The food poverty line was defined based on a food basket of 2500
kcal/day
6The exchange rate from the Interbank Burundi (s.a) of 1238 at the
time of the survey was used : www.interbankbdi.com
7http://data.worldbank.org/indicator/AG.CON.FERT.ZS (last accessed on 13 June 2016)
8Information from the regional agricultural office (Karuzi) on
prices (in 2012) of fertilisers before the subsidy programme which
is currently applied on fertiliser sector in Burundi (since august
2012).
9Farmers could not remember all the food items bought during the
survey year.
10https://onlinecourses.science.psu.edu/stat501/node/347 (last
accessed on 10th November, 2016)
Figure 1: Farm quartiles and
their respective shares in overall production per crop (%).
Figure 2: Household labour
and farm efficiency.
Figure 3: Farm size (m²) and efficiency levels in small-scale farms.
|
Overall mean |
Farm size categories |
F-test |
|||
Quartile I |
Quartile II |
Quartile III |
Quartile IV |
|||
Age of the head of household (years) |
43.47 (15.56) |
42.90 (14.76) |
43.35 (15.54) |
44.22 (16.09) |
43.39 (15.85) |
0.667 |
Household size (number of persons) |
5.26 (2.35) |
4.51bcd (2.08) |
5.08acd (2.30) |
5.45abd (2.30) |
5.97abc (2.40) |
38.827*** |
Farm household workers (number) |
2.47 (1.20) |
2.10cd (0.80) |
2.34cd (1.079) |
2.56abd (1.28) |
2.86abc (1.39) |
40.243*** |
Dependency ratio (%) |
51.31 (30.36) |
52.07 (30.81) |
50.44 (29.04) |
50.84 (32.39) |
51.88 (29.14) |
0.362 |
Household adult equivalents |
4.21 (1.96) |
3.47bcd (1.59) |
4.04acd (1.87) |
4.37abd (1.95) |
4.97abc (2.09) |
58.668*** |
|
|
|
|
|
|
c²-test |
Gender household head (% male) |
78.03 |
76.2 |
73.1 |
80.9 |
80.8 |
13.254** |
Symbols indicate significant differences at ***: p-value ≤ 0.01, **: p-value ≤0.05, *: p-value ≤ 0.10 |
Table 1: Basic household characteristics (n=2130; sd. in parentheses).
|
Overall mean |
Farm size categories |
F-test |
|||
Quartile I |
Quartile II |
Quartile III |
Quartile IV |
|||
Agricultural land (hectare) |
0.71 (0.58) |
0.19bcd (0.06) |
0.41acd (0.06) |
0.70abd (0.10) |
1.51abc (0.63) |
1690.56*** |
Seed expenditure (USD) |
23.39 (35.57) |
14.63cd (24.38) |
20.57cd (24.80) |
25.40abd (33.91) |
32.95abc (50.26) |
26.173*** |
Labour expenditure (USD) |
26.23 (26.22) |
9.33bcd (24.37) |
18.39acd (38.06) |
28.44abd (46.61) |
48.78abc (71.57) |
65.440*** |
Expenditure on chemicals (USD) |
10.57 (25.22) |
5.92bcd (20.94) |
10.13ac (21.92) |
12.95ab (26.00) |
13.29a (30.29) |
9.859*** |
|
|
|
|
|
|
c²-test |
Extension training (%yes) |
10.00 |
6.90 |
10.30 |
8.10 |
14.60 |
20.497*** |
Anti-erosion methods(%yes) |
38.40 |
30.40 |
38.70 |
43.50 |
41.00 |
18.572*** |
Access to credit (% yes) |
5.30 |
4.90 |
5.60 |
4.70 |
5.80 |
0.977 |
Membership agro- cooperative (% yes) |
13.80 |
13.10 |
13.90 |
14.30 |
13.70 |
0.312 |
Symbols indicate significant differences at ***: p-value ≤ 0.01, **: p-value ≤0.05, *: p-value ≤ 0.10 |
Table 2: Agricultural investment and production techniques (n=2130; sd. in parentheses).
Farm income (USD) |
Overall mean |
Farm size categories |
F-test |
|||
Quartile I |
Quartile II |
Quartile III |
Quartile IV |
|||
Market value food crops (USD) |
551.99 (535.41) |
271.17bcd (312.36) |
435.82acd (402.89) |
615.58abd (533.08) |
885.27abc (629.41) |
156.788*** |
Cash crop income (USD) |
16.04 (47.17) |
9.37d (37.96) |
15.10d (45.88) |
14.90d (40.54) |
24.81abc (59.97) |
9.996*** |
Non-farm (including off-farm) income (USD/year) |
82.60 (244.91) |
99.99 (290.98) |
80.85 (253.47) |
74.60 (203.46) |
74.95 (222.56) |
1.268** |
Annual farm household income (USD/year) |
650.63 (595.69) |
380.53bcd (426.55) |
531.77acd (479.65) |
705.09abd (585.28) |
985.03abc (681.44) |
117.669*** |
Share of non-farm (off-farm) income (%) |
29.69 (24.93) |
44.08bcd (28.93) |
29.59ad (23.47) |
23.99a (19.52) |
18.50ab (18.50) |
40.757*** |
Land productivity (USD/ha) |
1043.73 (1331.31) |
1598.19bcd (2190.19) |
1064.97ad (997.76) |
889.63ad (753.75) |
621.87abc (474.00) |
54.962*** |
Labour productivity (USD/worker) |
283.33 (276.70) |
193.22bcd (216.97) |
250.17acd (244.10) |
308.43abd (278.20) |
381.68abc (321.09) |
48.266*** |
Symbols indicate significant differences at ***: p-value ≤ 0.01, **: p-value ≤0.05, *: p-value ≤ 0.10 |
Table 3: Household annual income (n=2130; sd. in parentheses).
|
Overall mean |
Farm size categories |
F-test |
|||
Quartile I |
Quartile II |
Quartile III |
Quartile IV |
|||
Energyα(kcal/adult equivalent/day) |
2474 (32.40) |
1842cd (19.70) |
2226cd (28.00) |
2654abc (35.20) |
3172abc (46.90) |
25.959*** |
Incomeβ(USD/adult equivalent/year) |
177.54 (25.20) |
132.20cd (16.90) |
159.80cd (20.70) |
190.47abd (27.40) |
227.69abc (35.60) |
25.959*** |
Symbols indicate significant differences at ***: p-value ≤ 0.01, **: p-value ≤0.05, *: p-value ≤ 0.10 α: the reference value is the food poverty line (2500kcal per adult equivalent a day =14.95USD/30days) β: the reference value is the overall poverty line (18.25 USD/month x 12 months =219 USD/year) |
Table 4: Food security by farm size categories.
Land deciles |
Area cultivated (m²) |
Homogenous groups (mean efficiency scores) |
|||||
Group 1 |
Group 2 |
Group 3 |
Group 4 |
Group 5 |
Group 6 |
||
X |
20 902 |
0.41 |
|||||
IX |
12 228 |
0.43 |
0.43 |
||||
VIII |
9 143 |
0.43 |
0.43 |
0.43 |
|||
VII |
7 264 |
0.46 |
0.46 |
0.46 |
|||
VI |
5 924 |
0.48 |
0.48 |
0.48 |
|||
V |
4 847 |
0.48 |
0.48 |
0.48 |
|||
IV |
3 925 |
0.50 |
0.50 |
||||
III |
2 954 |
0.54 |
0.54 |
||||
II |
2 191 |
0.57 |
0.57 |
||||
I |
1 171 |
0.63 |
Table 5: Tukey range test in efficiency scores by land decile.
Land deciles (m²) |
Share of agricultural income |
Standard Efficiency scores |
Corrected Efficiency scores |
Poverty indicators |
||
Poverty Incidence |
Poverty gap |
Poverty severity |
||||
1 171 |
0.45 |
0.62 |
0.63 |
0.86 |
0.57 |
0.42 |
2 191 |
0.62 |
0.60 |
0.57 |
0.84 |
0.56 |
0.41 |
2 954 |
0.66 |
0.56 |
0.54 |
0.80 |
0.47 |
0.33 |
3 925 |
0.71 |
0.54 |
0.50 |
0.75 |
0.42 |
0.27 |
4 847 |
0.74 |
0.53 |
0.48 |
0.80 |
0.44 |
0.29 |
5 924 |
0.74 |
0.50 |
0.48 |
0.74 |
0.38 |
0.23 |
7 264 |
0.77 |
0.51 |
0.46 |
0.72 |
0.36 |
0.22 |
9 143 |
0.78 |
0.47 |
0.43 |
0.71 |
0.34 |
0.20 |
12 228 |
0.80 |
0.47 |
0.43 |
0.66 |
0.29 |
0.16 |
20 902 |
0.84 |
0.46 |
0.41 |
0.58 |
0.20 |
0.10 |
7 055 |
0.70 |
0.53 |
0.49 |
0.75 |
0.40 |
0.26 |
Table 6: Farm efficiency and household poverty.
Variables |
Coefficient estimate |
t-test |
VIF |
Intercept |
6.61e+04 |
3.22** |
|
Agricultural expenditures |
3.16 e-01 |
5.74*** |
1.12 |
Efficiency scores |
2.49 e+05 |
7.89*** |
1.06 |
Simmons index |
-2.17 e+05 |
-6.12*** |
1.04 |
Land available |
7.62 e+00 |
8.43*** |
1.17 |
Residual standard error |
226488.304 |
|
|
Root MSE |
226488.304 |
|
|
Multiple R-squared |
0.067 |
|
|
Adjusted R-squared |
0.065 |
|
|
Symbols indicate significant differences at ***: p-value ≤ 0.01, **: p-value ≤0.05, *: p-value ≤ 0.10 |
Table 7: 2SLS estimates for explaining household welfare (dependant variable: income per adult equivalent).
- Hedden-Dunkhorst B, Mollel NM (1999) Small scale farming
and extension in south africa's northern province. South African Journal of
Agricultural Extension 28: 93-107.
- Mellor JW (2014) High rural population density Africa - What are the growth requirements and who participates?. Food Policy 48: 66-75.
- Wiggins S, Kirsten J, Llambí L (2010) The Future of Small Farms. World Development 38: 1341-1348.
- Verschelde M, D'Haese M, Rayp G, Vandamme E (2012)
Challenging small scale farming: A non-parametric analysis of the (inverse)
relationship between farm productivity and farm size in Burundi. Journal of
Agricultural Economics 11: 261-287.
- Lipton M (2010) From Policy Aims and Small-farm Characteristics to Farm Science Needs. World Development 38: 1399-1412.
- Hazell PBR (2005) Is there a future for small farms?. Agricultural Economics 32: 93-101.
- Rosset PM (1999) The Multiple Functions and Benefits of Small Farm Agriculture. Policy brief 4 Institute for Food and Development Policy, Oakland, CA USA.
- Bravo-ureta BE, Pinheiro AE (1997) Technical, economic, and allocative efficiency in peasant farming: evidence from the dominican republic. The Developing Economies 35: 48-67.
- Mellor JW (1976) The New Economics of Growth: A Strategy for India and the Development World. Cornell University Press, Ithaca, NY.
- Robbins P, Ferris RSA (2003) The impact of globalisation on the agricultural sector of East and Central African countries. International Institute of Tropical agriculture, Ibadan, Nigeria.
- World Bank T (2007) World Development Report 2008: Agriculture for Development. The World Bank, Washington.
- Kirsten J, Sartorius K (2002) Linking agribusiness and small-scale farmers in developing countries: Is there a new role for contract farming?. Development Southern Africa 19: 503-529.
- Narayanam S, Gulati A (2002) Globalization and the Smallholders: A review of the Issues, Approaches and Tentative Conclusion. MSSD Discussion Paper No. 50 Food Policy Research Institute, Washington DC.
- Jayne TS, Yamano T, Weber MT, Tschirley D, Benfica R, et al. (2003) Smallholder income and land distribution in Africa: implications for poverty reduction strategies. Food Policy 28: 253-275.
- Glover D, Kusterer K (1990) Small farmers Big business: Contract Farming and Rural Development. The MacMillan Press LTD, Great Britain.
- Oketch JS, Polzer T (2002) Conflict and Coffee in Burundi. In: Lind J, Sturman K (ed.), Scarcity and Surfeit, The Ecology of Africa's Conflicts. Institute for Security Studies South Africa.
- MINAGRIE (2011) Agriculture et Development du monde rural. République du Burundi, Bujumbura.
- Verschelde M, D’Haese M, Rayp G, Vandamme E (2013) Challenging Small-Scale Farming: A Non-Parametric Analysis of the (Inverse) Relationship Between Farm Productivity and Farm Size in Burundi. Journal of AGricultural Economics 64: 319-342.
- Valdés A, Foster W (2010) Reflections on the Role of Agriculture in Pro-Poor Growth. World Development 38: 1362-1374.
- Pedro PS (2011) Investing in Agriculture in Burundi: Improving food security and conditions for women farmers. Oxfam, Bujumbura.
- Ricker-Gilbert J, Jumbe C, Chamberlin J (2014) How does population density influence agricultural intensification and productivity? Evidence from Malawi. Food Policy 48: 114-128.
- Buse RC, Salathe LE (1978) Adult Equivalent Scales: An Alternative Approach. American Journal of Agricultural Economics 60: 460-468.
- Weisell R, Dop MC (2012) The Adult Male Equivalent concept and its application to Household Consumption and Expenditures Surveys (HCES). Food and Nutrition Bulletin 33: 157-162.
- Niragira S, D'Haese M, D'Haese L, Ndimubandi J, Desiere S, et al. (2015) Food for Survival: Diagnosing Crop Patterns to Secure Lower Threshold Food Security Levels in Farm Households of Burundi. Food and nutrition bulletin 36: 196-210.
- Demetriou D (2014) The Development of an Integrated Planning and Decision Support System (IPDSS) for Land Consolidation. Springer, Switzerland.
- Simar L, Wilson PW (2000) A general Methodology for bootstrapping in non-parametric frontier models. Journal of Applied Statistics 27: 779-802.
- Bundervoet T (2006) Estimating Poverty in Burundi. Households in Conflict Network; Working Paper 20, The Institute of Development Studies - at the University of Sussex - Falmer - Brighton - BN1 9RE.
- Greenland S (2000) An introduction to instrumental variables for epidemiologists. International Journal of Epidemiology 29: 722-729.
- Angrist JD, Imbens WG, Rubin BD (1996) Identification of Causal Effects Using Instrumental Variables. Journal of American Statistical Association 91: 444-455.
- Abdulai A, Huffman W (2000) Structural Adjustment and Economic Efficiency of Rice Farmers in Northern Ghana. Economic Development and Cultural Change 48: 503-520.
- Charnes A, Cooper WW, Rhodes E (1978) Measuring the efficiency of decision making units. European Journal of Operational Research 2: 429-444.
- Banker RD, Charnes A, Cooper WW (1984) Some Models for estimating technical and scale efficiencies in data envelopmet analysis. Management Sciences 30: 1078-1092.
- Murillo-Zamorano LR (2004) Economic Efficiency and Frontier Techniques. Journal of Economic surveys 18: 33-77.
- Simar L, Wilson PW (2008) Statistical Inference in Nonparametric Frontier Models: Recent Developments and Perspectives.
- Cochet H (2001) Crises et Révolutions Agricoles au Burundi. Karthala, Paris.
- Cazals C, Florens JP, Simar L (2002) Nonparametric frontier estimation: a robust approach. Journal of Econometrics 106: 1-25.
- Veettil PC, Speelman S, van Huylenbroeck G (2012) Estimating the Impact of Water Pricing on Water Use Efficiency in Semi-arid Cropping System: An Application of Probabilistically Constrained Nonparametric Efficiency Analysis. Water Resources Management 27: 55-73.
- Simar L, Wilson PW (1998) Sensitivity Analysis of Efficiency Scores: How to Bootstrap in Nonparametric Frontier Models. Management Science 44: 49-61.
- Wu D, Olson DL (2008) A comparison of stochastic dominance and stochastic DEA for vendor evaluation. International Journal of Production Research 46: 2313-2327.
- Bruni ME, Conforti D, Beraldi P, Tundis E (2009) Probabilistically constrained models for efficiency and dominance in DEA. International Journal of Production Economics 117: 219-228.
- Wu D, Lee CG (2010) Stochastic DEA with ordinal data applied to a multi-attribute pricing problem. European Journal of Operational Research 207: 1679-1688.
- Gharakhani M, Kazemi I, Alizadeh Haji H (2011) A robust DEA model for measuring the relative efficiency of Iranian high schools. Management Science Letters 1: 389-404.
- Mugera A, Ojede A (2011) Agricultural Productivity Growth in Africa: Is Efficiency Catching-up or Lagging Behind?. 2011 Conference (55th), Melbourne, Australian Agricultural and Resource Economics ociety.
- Foster J, Greer J, Thorbecke E (1984) A class of decomposable poverty measures. Econometrica 52: 761-766.
- Foster J, Greer J, Thorbecke E (2010) The Foster-Greer-Thorbecke (FGT) poverty measure: 25 years later. Journal of Economic Inéquality 8: 491-524.
- Asogwa BC, Umeh JC, Okwoche VA (2012) Poverty and Efficiency among the farming Households in Nigeria: A Guide for Poverty Reduction Policy. Current Research Journal of Economic Theory 4: 6-10.
- FAO (2015) Country fact sheet on food and agriculture policy trends. Bujumbura.
- Tizikara C, Wilcock D, Habyarimana PC
(2007) Needs Assessment and Action plan for Improving Agricultural Research and
Technology Transfer. World Bank, Rwanda.
- IMF (2014) Country reports 14/293. In: 2014 Article IV Consultation, Bujumbura.
- Baghdadli I, Harborne B, Rajadel T (2008) Breaking the cycle: A strategy for conflict- sensitive rural growth in Burundi. The World Bank, Washington.
- Niragira S (2011) Optimizing land use among small scale farms through agricultural specialization in the north of Burundi Ghent University, Ghent.
- Benjamin D (1994) Can unobserved land quality explain the inverse productivity relationship?. Journal of Development Economics 46: 51-84.
- Sen AK (1975) Employment, Technology, and Development. Oxford University Press.
- Lamb R (2003) Inverse productivity: Land quality, labor markets, and measurement error. Journal of Development Economics 71: 71-95.
- Barrett C, Bellemare M, Hou J (2010) Reconsidering conventional explanations of the inverse productivity-size relationship. World Development 38: 88-97.